Free Trade and Imperialism: the cotton industry and British foreign policy, 1858–98
Introduction
In the period of 1784–86 the export of cotton goods from Great Britain
amounted to around £760,000. This represented around six per cent of the
export trade in manufactured goods; in contrast, wool brought in £3.7
million, almost 30 per cent of the total. In 1854–56, the value of the
cotton trade had grown by more than 45 times and represented over a
third of the value of the British export trade. Woollen goods, exports
of which grew by a mere three times in the same period, now represented
a mere tenth of British export
value.Ralph
Davis, The Industrial Revolution and British Overseas Trade
(Leicester: Leicester University Press, 1979).
The
intervening period had seen the development and widespread adoption of
steam power and a range of other technical innovations that transformed
the textiles industry from handicrafts performed on small scales the
world over to massive industrial enterprises increasingly concentrated
in particular areas of the world. Yet this does not tell the whole
story. Had the change been simply a matter of new technologies
introduced to textiles industries, one might have expected the wool and
cotton industries to grow in proportion with one another; and, as wool
can be produced natively in the British Isles while cotton requires
particular climatic conditions not found in northern Europe (or, indeed,
the northern United States), wool might be expected to remain the
dominant industry. Instead, to explain the growth of the cotton industry
it is necessary to look at additional factors: pre-existing networks of
trade, patterns of capital investment, favourable tariff regimes, and
Britain’s growing international political dominance that provided it
with controlled markets and later, supplies of raw materials.
British involvement with the international cotton trade had begun during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, with the growth of imports of cotton from India as the British presence in the region grew. At this stage, India was both a source of raw cotton and a major producer of cotton textiles for export. Cotton grown in various parts of the world was also imported to Britain and to the rest of Europe for the production of cotton textiles (including fustian, a mixture of cotton and linen). In all of these cases the manufacture was at a small scale prior to the development in the eighteenth century of various technological enhancements that began to increase the speed and regularity with which raw cotton could be spun into yarn and yarn could be woven into cloth.
The import of Indian cotton textiles into the British Isles by the East
India Company led to protests by domestic manufacturers and eventually
in 1700 to the passing of an Act of Parliament banning the import of
finished cotton textiles but not of raw cotton. This protectionist
policy encouraged the development of British cotton manufacturing to the
point that eventually British imports to India were able to compete with
domestic manufacture, and has been called ‘one of the key episodes in
the Great Divergence’ in living standards between Asia and
Europe.Stephen
Broadberry and Bishnupriya Gupta, ‘Cotton Textiles and the Great
Divergence: Lancashire, India and Shifting Competitive Advantage,
1600-1850’, 2005
<http://www.cepr.org/active/publications/discussion_papers/dp.php?dpno=5183>.
In Great Britain itself, the industry quickly became concentrated in
certain areas, including but not limited to Lancashire and the
northwest, due to the convergence of a number of factors. The region
benefitted from international trade links, in particular Liverpool, a
port whose importance had been cemented by its central role in the
Atlantic slave trade, controlling more than sixty percent of the British
trade by
1795.Eric
Williams, Capitalism & Slavery, 2nd edn (Chapel Hill: University of
North Carolina Press, 1994), pp. 34–38.
It also
had an existing wool industry whose technical advances could be shared
by the cotton industry, as well as providing a potential workforce for
the mills. As the industry increasingly relied on steam rather than
water power, the presence of nearby coal and iron mining was a further
advantage, and, after the 1830s as Lancashire became a pioneering region
in the development of railways, growth was able to accelerate
further.D.
A. Farnie, The English Cotton Industry and the World Market (Oxford:
Clarendon, 1979), pp. 45–54.
During the nineteenth century, British political opinion swung away from
the protectionist policies of earlier eras in favour of an overarching
principle of free trade, linked to the liberal political philosophies
developed in the same period. This policy had been controversial as late
as the 1840s, with the success of the campaign against the protectionist
Corn Laws leading to a split in the Conservative Party over the issue.
Nevertheless, by the end of the century it had become a central
principle in British policy not only domestically but internationally; a
free trade treaty had been signed between France and the United Kingdom
in 1860, followed by a series of similar bilateral agreements with other
European powers. Members of Parliament, in a debate on the Congo Free
State in 1908, could speak not only of their concern for the interests
of humanity, but also for the interests of
trade.Hansard,
‘House of Commons Debate on the Congo Free State’, 26 February 1908
<https://hansard.parliament.uk/commons/1908-02-26/debates/00dd9ca8-409f-4f67-bc24-823715fe3d4a/CongoFreeState>.
Consequently, during this period, tariffs within the empire were
abandoned, contributing to the ability of British cotton manufacturers
to undercut those in
India.Peter
J. Cain, ‘British Free Trade, 1850–1914: Economics and Policy’, Recent
Findings of Research in Economic Social History, 29, 1999
<https://files.ehs.org.uk/wp-content/uploads/2020/07/29061005/Cain29a.pdf>.
Nevertheless, it would be simplistic to assume that the interests of the British empire were in every case the interests of British industry, in part or as a whole. On the one hand, politicians and civil servants and even industrialists may genuinely have believed in free trade as a progressive or even humanitarian ideal; on the other, the interests of any particular branch of industry did not necessarily align with those of industry as a whole, nor were long-term and short-term interests always compatible. A distinction must therefore be drawn, in answering this question, between cases where industrialists were self-consciously able to influence British policy to their own advantage, and those where policy was determined by other factors but happened to support the interests of the cotton industry.
Historiography
The contemporary interpretation, one which was held by historians well
into the twentieth century, was that Britain’s imperial expansion during
much of the nineteenth century was unintentional, ‘a fit of absence of
mind’.John
Robert Seeley, The Expansion of England (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 2010)
<https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511783159>.
This began to be challenged from the 1950s onwards by the work of
Gallagher and
Robinson,John
Gallagher and Ronald Robinson, ‘The Imperialism of Free Trade’,
Economic History Review, 6.1 (1953), 1–15
<https://doi.org/10.2307/2591017>.
arguing
that there were instead different forms of imperialism which varied in
relative prevalence over time. In doing so, they criticized both the
traditional view of imperialism and the anti-imperialist interpretation
(e.g., J. A.
HobsonImperialism,
1902.
; Vladimir
Lenin‘Imperialism:
The Highest Stage of Capitalism’, in Collected Works (Moscow: Progress
Publishers, 1964).
) that still presumed that
British imperialism had only begun to grow towards the end of the
century.
In Gallagher and Robinson’s analysis, while the extension of political
dominance over large parts of Africa from the 1880s onwards was
unquestionably imperialism, so too were the treaties of free trade with
Persia and Turkey and the dependence of large parts of the world on
British capital. Nor could the state interest in Indian economic
development be squared with a supposed policy of laissez-faire.
Instead, imperial influence shifted between formal and informal modes in
different regions according to which best served imperial interests. In
this model, a policy of free trade was adopted where, and to the extent
that, it served British
interests,Peter
Harnetty, Imperialism and Free Trade (Manchester: Manchester
University Press, 1972), pp. 2–6.
while also
serving as an ideological justification: Britain as a defender of
liberty and beacon of scientific progress.
This model has formed the basis for most analysis of the British Empire
since the 1950s, although not without criticism, in particular in terms
of whether, and to what extent, private interests came into conflict
with national interests. For example, it has sometimes been assumed,
based on the Gallagher and Robinson model, that the shift from
‘informal’ to ‘formal’ imperialism would be made only in situations
where national interests, rather than private business interests, were
threatened.Bernard
Porter, The Lion’s Share: A Short History of British Imperialism,
1850–1983, 2nd edn (Longman, 1984); quoted in John Darwin, ‘Imperialism
and the Victorians: The Dynamics of Territorial Expansion’, English
Historical Review, 112.447 (1997), 614–42
<https://doi.org/10.1093/ehr/cxii.447.614>.
Against this public–private dichotomy, and rejecting the idea that the
tendency towards formal imperialism towards the end of the century was
driven by peripheral rather than metropolitan factors, Cain and Hopkins
proposed a model of ‘gentlemanly capitalism’, tying together landed
property, industrial capital, and the British
government.Peter
J. Cain and Antony G. Hopkins, British Imperialism: Innovation and
Expansion, 1688–1914 (Harlow: Longman, 1993), pp.
8–10.
Cain and Hopkins themselves encountered
criticism for the potential oversimplification of their model; however,
both they and their critics accepted the underlying premise of Gallagher
and Robinson of a system of informal versus formal
empire.Darwin.
The history of British imperialism in this period is also intertwined
with the ideology of free trade. This had become an increasingly
important ideal from the late eighteenth century onwards, with a growing
influence on British policy that was very much connected to liberal
ideas of good political governance. However, it was not a monolithic
institution that could be contrasted against a unified protectionist
bloc; the conflict cannot be summarized as one between free-traders in
industry and protectionists in government, nor as the British Empire
uniformly supporting free trade and the rest of the world unanimously
opposing; as with the preference for formal versus informal empire, the
boundaries between private and state interests were blurred. The British
government included supporters of free trade, who in turn came into
conflict with the cotton industry when its representatives demanded
greater state intervention than could be
justified.See,
e.g., Harnetty, Imperialism and Free Trade.
Similarly, while some advocates of free trade hoped for a Southern
victory in the American Civil War against the protectionist North,
others, like the Economist, a free trade magazine founded to promote
the abolition of the Corn Laws, were vocally opposed to the South and
its dependence on slavery. Humanitarianism, another great driver of
imperial policy, was at times in conflict with free trade; at others,
though, they found themselves aligned, with liberal governance and
political economy being conceived of as not only more profitable, but
more humane, than its alternatives.
Reframing the question of British foreign policy in terms of the formal–informal dichotomy, then, presents several questions. To what extent was the British cotton industry dependent on overseas activity, both for raw materials and for a market for their products; to what extent were they able to influence the British government in its policies both within and without the Empire in order to advance their own interests; and to what extent did this influence take the form of formal imperialism (i.e., assertion of explicit political control) versus informal imperialism (free trade agreements, ‘unequal treaties’, and the like).
India
Between the late eighteenth and mid-nineteenth centuries, India became the most significant of British imperial possessions. It encompassed territories spreading for thousands of kilometres; beyond India proper, it included the Aden Settlement to the west, governed as part of Bombay, and later Burma in the east. Much of British policy during this period was influenced by the need to protect India and the trade routes to it; not only Aden but Zanzibar and the Cape Colony drew some of their importance from Anglo-Indian trade, and this was also a factor in the construction of the Suez Canal in the 1860s. This growing importance was also reflected in the transfer of governance in 1858 from the East India Company to the British government proper, in the wake of the Company’s poor handling of the Indian Rebellion of the previous year.
From a very early stage domestic Indian producers of cotton had an
advantage over imported British cotton, as the cost of transport made
imports prohibitive. This applied both to transporting finished cloth
from Britain to India, as well as the cost of transporting raw cotton to
Britain for manufacture, reflected in the higher cost of raw cotton in
Britain than in India. The higher cost of living in Great Britain
additionally meant that labour was significantly cheaper in India.
However, between 1770 and 1830 the technological advances increased
productivity to the point that, despite this, British-produced cotton
was able to compete with Indian
cotton.Broadberry
and Gupta.
This competition was supported at all stages by state intervention; at
first, this took the form of protectionist policies, both import duties
and outright bans on imports. Later as industrial advances were made
these too were prohibited by law from being export. Finally, during the
period in which the British manufacturing industry became able to
compete with India, the ideology of free trade became increasingly
established, and India was forced to implement trade policies agreeable
to the
metropole.Cain.
This allowed Britain an effective monopoly in its colonies, and it was
upon this and not outright technical superiority which the cotton
industry
depended.Eric
J. Hobsbawm, Industry and Empire, Rev. edn. (London: Penguin, 1999),
p. 36.
Moreover, Lancashire industrialists were
not without political power, and were able to intervene in politics on a
number of occasions in order to maintain their position in colonial
markets, particularly India. Indeed, between enfranchisement in 1832 and
the division of the constituency in 1885, the majority of Manchester’s
Members of Parliament were directly (as owners) or indirectly (for
example, as lawyers) involved in the cotton industry, and the
correspondence of Charles Wood, Secretary of State for India from
1859–66, reveals a regular stream of communication with the Manchester
Chamber of Commerce and other interested
bodies.F.
W. S. Craig, British Parliamentary Election Results 1832–1885, 2nd edn
(London: Macmillan, 1989); Harnetty, Imperialism and Free
Trade.
During the half-century after 1813, when the East India Company’s trade
monopoly was abolished, a tariff system was maintained that was weighted
significantly in favour of British exporters. This took the form of a
relatively low tariff on cotton goods and cotton yarn into India, a
similarly low tariff on raw cotton out of India, but high tariffs on
cotton goods from India. By the 1850s the imbalance was presenting a
problem for the Indian government, which was regularly required to
operate at a deficit and becoming increasingly
indebted.Harnetty,
Imperialism and Free Trade, pp. 7–8.
This was the beginning of a political conflict that lasted for several
decades, involving both overt and hidden motivations. When the tariff on
yarn was raised from 3½ percent to 5 percent in 1859, Manchester
industrialists expressed their concern through the local Chamber of
Commerce, arguing that this was both counter to the principle of free
trade and (as a result) counter to the interests of both Britain and
India.Quoted
in Harnetty, Imperialism and Free Trade, p. 11.
Their colleagues in Liverpool were more tolerant but nevertheless
expressed the hope that the tariffs would be removed as soon as
possible. Nevertheless, the tariff on yarn was raised further, to 10
percent, in 1860, prompting further protests.
The debate over tariffs continued over the next two decades, with the
impact of the American Civil War on the cotton supply having a role in
the issue. The dispute occurred on multiple fronts; both with regard to
the necessity of tariffs at all, and the appropriate levels for them,
but also the division of tariffs between different types of goods. For
example, the tariff on yarn was generally different from that on
finished goods, yarn being a raw material; in addition, proposals were
put forward to tax differing qualities at different rates, with the
reasoning that finer yarns and cloths were generally made by British
manufacturers and coarser ones by Indians, since India generally lacked
the machinery for finer qualities. In 1882 the Indian import tariffs
were abolished; publicly it was claimed that ‘English experience … had
shown the benefits of a free trade policy’, and that this would
stimulate the construction of railways. However, the Viceroy and the
Finance Member of the Indian Legislative Council admitted in private
that the deciding factor had been the political pressure from
Manchester.Harnetty,
Imperialism and Free Trade; Peter Harnetty, ‘The Indian Cotton Duties
Controversy, 1894–1896’, English Historical Review, 77.305 (1962),
684–702
<https://doi.org/10.1093/ehr/lxxvii.cccv.684>.
In the 1890s the controversy was ignited once more, with the Indian
government again facing financial difficulties. As in the earlier
debate, the argument was framed in terms of free trade, which, while
benefitting British-based manufacturers, would also be to the benefit of
consumers. Nevertheless, while previously some free-trade proponents had
been willing to accept the necessity of tariffs for the purpose of
generating revenue so long as they did not amount to a policy of
protectionism, they were now opposed even to the introduction of a
half-percent tariff on limited classes of goods, a tariff intended to
balance out the expense to Indian manufacturers of import duties on
dyes. Furthermore, the debate was intensely focussed on cotton duties to
the exclusion of all others. Indeed, the Viceroy, Lord Elgin, wrote that
‘exclusion of the duties on cotton goods can be defended, … by no
argument that will be accepted here as valid, except one, i.e. that it
would be impossible to face Parliament with the proposition’. The cotton
industry now formed a powerful lobby, recognized even by the
under-Secretary of State for India, who claimed that ‘India is being
sacrificed to Lancashire’. On this occasion, too, it became a matter of
public debate and concern: Indian nationalism had been on the rise, and
more and more it was felt that ‘India was being made to suffer for the
sake of British interests’ and that this was undermining Indian loyalty
to Britain and the belief of Indians in the justice of British
rule.Harnetty,
‘The Indian Cotton Duties Controversy, 1894–1896’.
In the end, the conflict was resolved by retaining the tariffs on
imports, but applying an equivalent excise duty on Indian-manufactured
cotton goods.
Tariff policy was not the only area in which British cotton interests
attempted to influence the Indian government during this period. There
was ongoing pressure on the government to invest in infrastructural
improvements, particularly railways. The double standard was not lost on
Anglo-Indian officials: in 1866, the Governor-General complained that
‘everyone calls for more and more expenditure, while none are for more
taxation’.Quoted
in Harnetty, Imperialism and Free Trade.
Railway
investment in India was primarily intended for extraction of raw
materials, including cotton; as such, it became a renewed area of focus
after the outbreak of the American Civil War and the increased
importance of India as a source of raw cotton.
Increased investment in cotton agriculture itself was also a goal of
lobbying. It was not a new problem; attempts to improve the quality and
increase the quantity of Indian cotton had been under way since the
1840s, due both to concerns about the potential harm caused by an
American monopoly, as well as the desire to spend money within the
empire rather than without. However, the American war again brought a
renewed emphasis on the problem. American cotton was considered to be of
higher quality and as such several attempts were made to introduce
American cotton varieties into India. However, these were hampered both
by the climactic differences and, in some cases, the amateurism of
attempts to cultivate
them;Seth
Leacock and David G. Mandelbaum, ‘A Nineteenth Century Development
Project in India: The Cotton Improvement Program’, Economic Development
and Cultural Change, 3.4 (1955), 334–51
<https://doi.org/10.1086/449693>.
the Cotton
Supply Association, its critics claimed, had a tendency to assume that
having missionaries and consuls distribute seeds and leaflets in areas
with appropriate climatic conditions would result in the development of
successful cotton agriculture, regardless of the lack of infrastructure
that would be needed to make farming in these regions economically
viable.W.
O. Henderson, The Lancashire Cotton Famine 1861–65, 2nd edn
(Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1969), p.
38.
At the outbreak of war in America, the Manchester Chamber of Commerce
met with the Secretary of State for India, emphasizing the need to
stimulate cotton production. Their proposal was, first and foremost, to
improve India’s railway network. This, however, presented a number of
issues for the Indian government, not least the ongoing financial
difficulties. Indeed, despite these problems, the government had
recently borrowed several million pounds for railway construction, and
felt that anything more than this would be impossible while on the verge
of
bankruptcy.Peter
Harnetty, ‘The Imperialism of Free Trade: Lancashire, India, and the
Cotton Supply Question, 1861–1865’, Journal of British Studies, 6.1
(1966), 70–96
<https://doi.org/10.1086/385528>.
The
Secretary of State, also ideologically supportive of the principle of
free trade, was unwilling for the government to intervene any more than
necessary. As such, the Government put conditions on any state aid that
would be provided; first of all, that it would be directed at
improvements that could be realized in the next growing season, and
therefore excluding longer-term projects like roads, railways, and
canals; secondly, that it would not involve the state interfering with
or taking the role of private enterprise directly. Thus, proposals were
put forward involving grants for road improvement, and for merchants
based on the coast to improve their reach into the interior and cut out
middle-men. This, however, was insufficient for the Lancashire
interests, who via the Cotton Supply Association were advocating for not
only investment but legislative changes to allow more effective
enforcement of contract law and modifications to the ‘unsound and
oppressive system of land
tenure’.Quoted
in Harnetty, ‘The Imperialism of Free Trade: Lancashire, India, and the
Cotton Supply Question, 1861–1865’.
In particular,
demands were made for penal penalties for breach of contract and the
right to seize crops in order to recover
debts.Sven
Beckert, Empire of Cotton (Vintage, 2014), pp.
252–55.
These legal changes fitted into a
different model of the role of the state with regard to empire, one in
which government action was justifiable in order to produce favourable
conditions for business. The laws of supply and demand, argued the
Economist, could not be expected to work unless certain prerequisites
were met, and it would be no violation of free-trade principles for the
government to ensure those prerequisites were met: ‘Government does not
interfere to prevent the effect and operation of “supply and demand”,
but to create that operation to ensure that effect.’ India was
‘destitute of the ordinary economical capacities’, it was argued, in an
analogy comparing it to a blind and deaf
child.The
Economist (London, 4 October 1862), pp. 1093–94.
This view of Britain’s relationship to its colonial possessions was not
unusual; John Stuart Mill, a 35-year employee of the East India Company,
conceived of civil liberties as necessarily applying only to
‘member[s] of a civilized community’ in his work On Liberty. He
clarified that this was ‘meant to apply only to human beings in the
maturity of their faculties. We are not speaking of children…’ and, for
the same reason, excluded those ‘backward states…in which the race
itself may be considered as in its nonage.’ Therefore, the kind of
treatment that a European might expect was not applicable to others:
‘Despotism is a legitimate mode of government in dealing with
barbarians, provided the end be their
improvement.’John
Stuart Mill, On Liberty (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009)
<https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139149785>.
Lancashire interests were not entirely at odds with national ones,
however; while not everybody agreed with the Economist’s
interpretation of free trade, investment in railways could be justified
also by the need to move troops around the country, still a matter of
concern less than a decade after the Indian
Rebellion.Beckert,
p. 253.
And, indeed, cotton was such a significant
part of the British economy that the MP for Stockport was justified in
calling it ‘not a mere Lancashire question [but] a question of great
national importance’, in a Parliamentary debate calling for investment
into Indian river transport. Yet, the cotton industry tended to
underestimate what was being done by the Indian government, and to
overestimate the extent to which further state investment could be made,
as was pointed out in response by the Secretary of State for India in
the same
debate.Hansard,
‘House of Commons Debate on the Cotton Supply’, 19 June 1862
<https://hansard.parliament.uk/commons/1862-06-19/debates/8425fcff-7850-41cd-a722-d97c8dadad3b/TheCottonSupply>.
Nor were the legal changes entirely to the detriment of the Indian
people. Lobbying from the cotton industry contributed to the passing of
the first Factories Acts in India, in 1880 and 1891. The motivations
behind this intervention were not altruistic; British factories had been
regulated, in varying degrees, for several decades by this point, and
the new legislation began to apply similar restrictions in India,
including regulation of child labour. Significantly, pressure came not
only from business owners, but also from mill workers, recognizing the
influence of international competition on their own pay and working
conditions.Beckert,
pp. 411–12; Tirthankar Roy, Economic History of India, 1857–1947 (OUP
India, 2011), p. 198
<https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198074175.001.0001>.
North America
By the middle of the nineteenth century the southern United States had
far outstripped every other source of cotton in use by British industry.
By 1854–56 it provided more than 75 percent of British imports of raw
cotton; eighty years previously its share had been almost
nothing.Davis.
Yet this presented a number of issues for British industry. Unlike
India, the United States was not politically subordinate to Britain; its
tariffs could not be dictated by the metropole and, indeed, the two
countries fought a war between 1812 and 1814. Furthermore, the United
States had its own long-running internal debates over the dependence of
the Southern economy on slave labour, debates which would directly
impact on the production of cotton in the South. The importance of
American cotton to Britain was not lost to American planters; when civil
war broke out in 1861, exports were restricted in the hope of inducing
Britain to enter the war on the side of the
Confederacy.Brian
Holden Reid, The American Civil War and the Wars of the Industrial
Revolution (London: Cassell, 1999).
The cotton economy of the southern United States had grown in unison
with the mechanization of the industry, especially in northwest England;
while before the end of the eighteenth century its output had been
negligible, from the 1790s onwards it had been able to expand much
faster than other regions in order to meet the growing demand.
Lancashire was not the sole buyer for American cotton; the textiles
industry of the north-eastern United States was growing during the same
period. Nevertheless, the importance of Britain as a destination for raw
cotton was so great that the southern United States have been described
as a ‘dependent economy’ of
Lancashire.Hobsbawm,
Industry and Empire.
Concerns over the future of the American cotton supply had long predated
the outbreak of war; for several decades it had become increasingly
difficult for southern states to raise capital, for example for the
construction of railroads, as a result of what the Westminster Review
called a ‘shrewd calculation of the dangers … of a society whose
foundations are laid in injustice and violence’. The moral concern was
part of this; as with the British slave trade before its abolition,
slavery was held to be a negative influence on its owners and on the
society which permitted it, and not just on the slaves themselves. But,
more prosaically, a society dependent on slavery had a ‘treacherous
foundation’, in the words of the Cotton Supply
Association,Cotton
Supply Association, Fifth Annual Report of the Executive Committee
(Manchester: Cotton Supply Association, 1862).
carrying with it the risk of rebellion, and greater risk meant greater
interest rates, ‘plac[ing] the government of that State at a serious
disadvantage in the money market’, when compared with the northern
states where slavery was not
present.Westminster
and Foreign Quarterly Review (London, 1850), pp.
213–14.
The concern went beyond a simple
reluctance to invest; there was a recognition that dependence on a
single source of raw material was a danger for multiple reasons, and
this formed part of the impetus for investment in Indian and Egyptian
agriculture in the years before the outbreak of war.
Furthermore, investment in Southern business had legal risks involved;
Parliament had passed the Slave Trade Act in 1843, which extended the
1807 and 1833 bans on trading and owning of slaves, so that they would
apply to British subjects no matter where in the world they resided or
where the trade or ownership took place. This had a particular
significance for financing of the cotton industry, which was in many
cases based upon capital advances to growers from merchants, with these
advances using the grower’s slaves as collateral. This significance was
not lost on the British cotton industry, with the Liverpool-based
American Chamber of Commerce lobbying unsuccessfully against the
introduction of the
law.Beckert,
p. 223.
The balance of power between British industry and American agriculture
was not clearly understood prior to the war, at least on the American
side, which tended to overestimate its own importance to Britain. A
senator for South Carolina claimed in 1858 that ‘England would topple
headlong and carry the whole civilized world with her’ if Southern
cotton exports were
interrupted.Quoted
in Jay Sexton, Debtor Diplomacy: Finance and American Foreign Relations
in the Civil War Era 1837–1873 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005),
p. 136
<https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199281039.001.0001>.
It was thus the linchpin of Southern diplomacy during the civil war: on
the one hand, a Southern victory would (it was suggested) lead to a
transatlantic free trade agreement that would exclude the protectionist
north; on the other, an unofficial but widely-observed boycott of cotton
exports, combined with a Northern embargo, reduced British imports of
American cotton by 95 percent in 1862, compared with the high point of
1860. This was to no avail, however: while the majority of Britain’s
cotton imports before the war had been from North America, it had also
been developing alternative sources in India and Egypt which were able
to begin to take up the slack during the war years; in addition,
overproduction in the 1850s meant that British warehouses still held a
surplus of raw
cotton.Sexton,
pp. 136–38.
Nevertheless, the interruption of the
cotton supply did have an impact in Lancashire: seven out of ten
Manchester mills was forced to operate at less than its maximum
capacity, with one in six closing outright; 80,000 jobs were
lost.Allen
C. Guelzo, Fateful Lightning: A New History of the Civil War and
Reconstruction (OUP USA, 2012), p. 291.
The
South’s dependence on cotton diplomacy was not lost on the North,
either, who encouraged ongoing attempts to develop sources of cotton
elsewhere in the world, on the basis that it would weaken the South not
only in the short term, for the duration of the war, but also help to
prevent it from regaining power in the event of a Northern victory. The
Union government went so far as to export significant quantities of
cotton seed to England, via New York and later New
Orleans.Ricky-Dale
Calhoun, ‘Seeds of Destruction: The Globalization of Cotton as a Result
of the American Civil War’ (unpublished PhD Thesis, Kansas State
University, 2002), pp. 99–100
<http://krex.k-state.edu/dspace/bitstream/handle/2097/14956/RickyDaleCalhoun2012.pdf?sequence=1>.
The British response to the war was divided; while Britain had significant economic interests in the South, these were not without their counterpart in the North. One wing of public opinion, represented in the press by The Economist, argued that entering the war on the Confederate side would be the greater of two economic evils. According to the Economist, the mill closures were due not to the restricted supply, but rather a result of the years of overproduction which had saturated the market for cotton goods. On the other, propaganda campaigns centred in Lancashire pushed for official diplomatic recognition of the Confederacy, and, while Britain remained officially neutral, this did not prevent the commissioning of a number ships by the Confederate Navy, built on the Mersey, Thames, and Clyde. Finance for these came, in some cases, from an Anglo-American bank with its British branch based in Liverpool, Fraser, Trenholm, & Co; prior to the war its business had centred around the cotton trade.
Even in Lancashire, support for the Confederacy was not unanimous. For
some industrialists, the work of organizations like the Cotton Supply
Association was counterproductive at best; the ‘scientific’ principle of
free trade was the safest guarantee of stability: ‘[i]f they left the
matter to the natural arbitrament of supply and demand, they would have
no occasion to fear a dearth of
cotton’.Henderson,
p. 37.
And, while the traditional assumption
(represented by writers as diverse as Karl Marx and John Stuart Mill)
had been that middle class and aristocracy supported the Confederacy
while the working class supported the Union, the working class was no
more monolithic than their employers were. Nevertheless, though the
situation was more complex than the traditional analysis accounted for,
recent scholarship has rejected the claim that the working class was
overwhelmingly
pro-Confederacy.Cf.
R. J. M. Blackett, Divided Hearts: Britain and the American Civil War
(Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press, 2001); Mary Ellison,
Support for Secession (Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1972).
While some suspicions as to Northern
motives existed, there was a significant pro-Northern sentiment among
the working class in Lancashire and elsewhere, strengthened greatly by
the Emancipation Proclamation of 1863 that encouraged them to think of
the war as a war against not only slavery but one against tyranny in
general. This popular sentiment increased Parliamentary unwillingness to
intervene on the Confederate
side.Guelzo,
p. 297; Sexton, pp. 146–47.
However, public opinion in Britain was not unambiguously in favour of
the abolition of slavery. The Economist, although opposing
intervention on behalf of the Confederacy, expressed concerns about the
economic impact of abolition, calling it a ‘a trenchant and fearful
measure’ that would ‘inflict utter ruin and universal desolation on
those fertile
territories…’.The
Economist (London, 21 September 1861), pp.
1041–42.
Others, such as the Cotton Supply
Reporter, drew comparisons with the slave revolt of
Saint-Domingue,Beckert,
p. 265.
later renamed Haiti, during the French
Revolution, or with the experience of slave-dependent Caribbean colonies
like Jamaica since the abolition of slavery in the Empire. It was
expected that, as in Saint-Domingue and Jamaica, former slaves would
mostly rely on subsistence farming and produce only enough cotton to
supplement their incomes. Especially in the tropics, it was felt that
subsistence farming could so easily provide for most needs that the
Economist referred to it as a ‘perpetual poor law’, acting like a
‘minimum of
wages’.Beckert,
p. 267.
In short, without slavery, free farmers
would not be dependent on the cotton industry for a living; this was the
situation with the small-scale production in Brazil and India, for
example, which had been unable to compete with the American harvest
either in price or in quantity.
Nor did the end of the war receive an unambiguously positive reception,
with the Cotton Supply Reporter arguing, after the surrender of
several Confederate generals in April 1865, that the cessation of
hostilities would have a negative effect on the development of new
cotton sources; if progress had been ‘stubbornly neglected’ even in the
absence of American competition, it was even less likely to take place
once the American trade was restored. This was, it was felt, likely to
necessitate the abandonment of Indian cotton; the fault for this was
laid firmly at the feet of the British and Indian governments, and the
Secretary of State in particular, for his perceived unwillingness to
support the industry’s
interests.Cotton
Supply Reporter, Cotton Supply Reporter (Manchester, 1 May 1865), p.
1642.
The war also caused, or perhaps accelerated, a fundamental shift in the
way cotton was traded by Lancashire. While at the beginning of the
century, merchants had bought and sold particular shipments of cotton,
during the pre-war period a process of standardization took place that
meant that increasingly manufacturers could simply purchase particular
quantities of cotton of a specified quality, without concerning
themselves with the specifics of its source. The wartime shortages
brought about a further innovation, so that shipments were increasingly
bought and sold not only before delivery but potentially even before
they were harvested and shipped, an early form of futures trading. This
in turn allowed an increase in speculation, with knock-on effects in
other cotton-producing areas. Along with the growth in communications
networks (telegraph was Europe-wide and reached Cairo by 1863), this
prompted an increasing importance of ‘Liverpool prices’ for cotton
growers, which was only to increase as transatlantic and Indian
telegraph connections began to operate during the 1860s and
1870s.Beckert,
pp. 229–30, 249, 336.
Egypt
Egypt occupied a very different position in relation to the British Empire than did either India or the United States. For, while India had been a formal part of the British Empire from the 1850s if not earlier, Egypt was de jure part of the Ottoman Empire until 1914, when Ottoman entry into the First World War prompted Britain to declare it a protectorate in defence of the Suez Canal. Yet, on the other hand, while British capital was influential in the southern United States, American political authority remained strong enough to maintain independence, whereas the Ottomans were unable to prevent the establishment by Britain of a de facto protectorate over Egypt from 1882 onwards. For this reason, while the history of Egypt is directly relevant to the cotton industry in itself, it also provides a significant example of the workings of ‘informal empire’.
As with India, Egypt had a long history of cotton production, and by the
eighteenth century was producing quantities sufficient for both domestic
industry and export. However, the massive growth of the American cotton
industry had eclipsed it, rendering it relatively insignificant: prior
to the American Civil War, Indian cotton exports were four times larger
than Egyptian, and American exports thirty-five times higher. It was
only the outbreak of the war that reemphasized concerns about British
dependence on a single source and thus generated renewed interest in
other cotton-growing
regions.Edward
Mead Earle, ‘Egyptian Cotton and the American Civil War’, Political
Science Quarterly, 41.4 (1926), 520–45
<https://doi.org/10.2307/2142228>.
Egypt had not been the initial focus of attempts to expand cotton
production; as previously discussed, great hopes had been pinned on
India in the decades leading up to the American Civil War. Indeed, as
late as 1862, the Cotton Supply Association’s annual report dedicated
only a few paragraphs to Egypt, after nine pages on India; while it was
among the most promising territories outside India, there was, as yet,
little to show for it; nevertheless, progress had been made since the
previous report, and a representative of the Association had visited
Egypt and met with the Viceroy on the subject. The representative
reported that, while the climate and soil were suitable for large-scale
cotton cultivation, Egypt lacked modern machinery and, while labour was
plentiful, there was a shortage of skilled managers to supervise
production.Cotton
Supply Association, Ninth Annual Report of the Executive Committee
(Manchester: Cotton Supply Association, 1868).
However, with the reluctance of the British and Indian authorities to
invest in much-needed infrastructure, along with concerns on the part of
Lancashire manufacturers that increased agricultural output would
encourage Indian manufacturers at the expense of British ones, meant
that by the early 1860s these hopes were fading and Egypt was beginning
to take India’s place. The Egyptian variety of cotton was more desirable
to the manufacturers, the climate was more suitable, and the state of
Egyptian industry was such that it was unlikely to develop into a
competitor to Manchester. Increasingly, too, cotton cultivation was
being stimulated by the awareness of the American situation and the
consequent prices, rising to more than four times the pre-war situation
and not returning to normal until 1870, almost ten years after the
outbreak of
war.Earle.
Between 1860 and 1865, Egyptian cotton output had grown five times, with
cotton farms taking up 40 percent of agricultural land by
1864.Beckert,
p. 256.
Much of this was due to direct action from
the Ottoman governor of Egypt, Muhammad Sa‘id Pasha, who converted his
own landholdings into cotton farms and made major investments in
infrastructure and machinery.
The impact of the American Civil War on Egyptian industry was not wholly
favourable, however. High prices for raw cotton encouraged the expansion
of cotton farming at the expense of subsistence crops, which in turn
drove up prices on imported food. By 1865 the Cotton Supply Association
was raising concerns about the low quality being produced, as well as
the risk of soil exhaustion and the potential for complete collapse of
the Egyptian
industry.Cotton
Supply Reporter, Cotton Supply Reporter (Manchester, 1 June 1865), pp.
1664–65.
Nevertheless, the Association remained
hopeful, noting in the same article that exports had tripled in three
years. And, indeed, while the price of cotton fell again from 1866 when
the United States re-entered the market, it still remained above the
pre-war
price.Juan
R. I. Cole, Colonialism and Revolution in the Middle East (American
Univ in Cairo Press, 1999), p. 59.
The rush of investment in Egypt was also encouraged by the favourable
tariff regime; Egypt was still part of the Ottoman Empire and bound by
its free-trade treaty with
Britain,Roger
Owen, The Middle East in the World Economy, 1800–1914 (I. B. Tauris,
1993).
preventing the semi-autonomous Egyptian
government from applying the kind of protectionist policies that, for
example, the United States had in order to encourage development of
domestic industry. This had further-reaching effects than simply
prompting the growth of cotton exports; the influx of capital led to the
increasing dependence on foreign loans by the Egyptian government. In
order to ensure their timely repayment, in the mid-1870s the British and
French governments took shared control of state finances, along with the
railways and the port of Alexandria. This foreign domination fed
increasing nationalist unrest leading to an uprising in 1882, which in
turn provided the pretext for the establishment of a British
protectorate over
Egypt.Eric
J. Hobsbawm, The Age of Capital: 1848–1875 (Weidenfeld & Nicholson,
1995), pp. 125–27.
This went against long-standing
British preference; Palmerston had said in 1857, during his first period
as Prime Minister, that Britain ‘did not want the burden of governing
Egypt’ and that they should ‘abstain from a crusade of
conquest’.Quoted
in Ronald Hyam, Britain’s Imperial Century, 1815–1914, 3rd edn
(Springer, 2002), p. 108.
Yet it had long been a
matter of concern in British foreign policy; as one of two overland
routes to India (the other being via Syria and Mesopotamia), its
conquest by another power would have been ‘fatal … to the interests of
this country’ according to the Minister for War in
1799.Hyam,
p. 175.
The French construction of the Suez canal
was thus seen by the British government as being a negative development:
with control over the sea route to India and no other powers able to
compete in the East Asian trade, the canal could only hurt British
interests. British industrial interests did not agree: a faster and
safer route to India could only increase profits, on the
whole.Cotton
Supply Association, Ninth Annual Report of the Executive Committee;
quoted in Jonathan Graham Tate, ‘Industry, Technology and the Political
Economy of Empire: Lancashire Industrialists and the Cotton Supply
Question, c. 1850–1910’ (unpublished PhD Thesis, University of Aberdeen,
2015)
<http://digitool.abdn.ac.uk/webclient/DeliveryManager?pid=228009>.
As in India, the growing importance of cotton to the Egyptian economy entailed large-scale changes in the form of land tenure. Prior to the period of imperialism, land had often been owned collectively, with individuals, communities, and the state all having varying claims to different parcels of land. This tended to hamper any outright sale, and in order to encourage foreign investment it was necessary to replace this system with a less contentious one. The new laws also changed traditional practices around collection of debts; previously, peasants in arrears could not have their land seized; similar to the Indian case, after 1876 the law was ‘modernized’, which is to say brought into line with European norms, allowing land to be foreclosed upon in the case of late payment.
These legal changes, along with rising taxes on lands and interest rates
on loans, tended also to mean an increasing consolidation of land into
fewer, larger estates; these large estates grew to cover half of the
country by the end of the century. This, in turn, brought with it a
shift in the social position of the agricultural workers; where
previously they had had a right to the land and to its revenues,
increasingly they were wage workers entirely dependent on the landowner.
This differed from the situation in India and the United States, where
sharecropping was increasingly the predominant relationship between
cultivator and
capitalist;Timothy
Mitchell, Rule of Experts (University of California Press, 2002);
quoted in Beckert.
however, in each case, there
was a recognizable transition from a primarily subsistence-based,
small-scale agriculture, to one more dependent on commodity production.
Conclusion
As examined by Gallagher and Robinson, Cain and Hopkins, Darwin, and others, British imperialism took differing forms, depending on the needs of the time and place. The British cotton industry was inherently international, relying on tropical raw materials as well as overseas markets, and so it grew up intertwined with imperialism, both growing to fill new markets as new technology made British manufactures more competitive, and driving the expansion of colonial ventures as it outgrew existing sources of raw cotton.
The most important ideological reflection of this economic situation was the growing preference, after the late eighteenth century and especially after the 1840s, for ‘free trade’, which as a movement primarily concerned itself with opposing tariffs but also, to a lesser extent, other forms of ‘protective’ measures by government. Yet this was not a static and unyielding dictum; free trade supporters might accept the necessity of tariffs for revenue purposes, so long as they did not have a ‘protective’ effect; this was the case in the Indian controversies, where both the government and industry ostensibly supported a policy of free trade yet disagreed as to its implementation. Similar developments, with the positions more or less reversed, can be seen in the debates over government investment in transport infrastructure, for example, and increasingly a theoretical basis was developed to defend what might otherwise have seemed contradictory.
It is also important not to focus on the cotton industry to the exclusion of all other factors, or to presume it was all-powerful. It faced conflicts with foreign powers over control of its raw materials and its markets, as well as finding itself at the centre of the struggles of the increasingly-militant working class within the metropole. In turn, working-class support was cited in favour of imperial policies, particularly when it could be contrasted favourably with past militancy and disruption. Even between industrialists and politicians, controversy was found; it was by no means clear in all cases that the best interests of the British Empire were the precise interests of the cotton industry, or that free trade was best served by large-scale state support — particularly when this support was costly, as was often the case. Furthermore, in the case of the American Civil War, the cause of free trade was also the cause of slave labour, with many British free traders finding it impossible to reconcile the two positions.
Further investigation in this subject might centre on the free trade movement, particularly in its connections with both industry and government and in the discontinuities between its principles and the practical policies it advocated for; while various examples of this can be seen, for example in the case of India and the cotton tariffs, a focus on the cotton industry may obscure, or exaggerate, the full extent of double standards of this kind. Other areas of investigation might include working class organization and its relationship (positive or negative) to the ideologies of free trade, along with other ideals of nineteenth-century liberalism, like the humanitarian campaigns that led to the abolition of the Atlantic slave trade at the beginning of the century and outcry over the conditions in the Belgian Congo at the end of it.
References
Beckert, Sven, Empire of Cotton (Vintage, 2014)
Blackett, R. J. M., Divided Hearts: Britain and the American Civil War (Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press, 2001)
Broadberry, Stephen, and Bishnupriya Gupta, ‘Cotton Textiles and the Great Divergence: Lancashire, India and Shifting Competitive Advantage, 1600-1850’, 2005 <http://www.cepr.org/active/publications/discussion_papers/dp.php?dpno=5183>
Cain, Peter J., ‘British Free Trade, 1850–1914: Economics and Policy’, Recent Findings of Research in Economic Social History, 29, 1999 <https://files.ehs.org.uk/wp-content/uploads/2020/07/29061005/Cain29a.pdf>
Cain, Peter J., and Antony G. Hopkins, British Imperialism: Innovation and Expansion, 1688–1914 (Harlow: Longman, 1993)
Calhoun, Ricky-Dale, ‘Seeds of Destruction: The Globalization of Cotton as a Result of the American Civil War’ (unpublished PhD Thesis, Kansas State University, 2002) <http://krex.k-state.edu/dspace/bitstream/handle/2097/14956/RickyDaleCalhoun2012.pdf?sequence=1>
Cole, Juan R. I., Colonialism and Revolution in the Middle East (American Univ in Cairo Press, 1999)
Cotton Supply Association, Fifth Annual Report of the Executive Committee (Manchester: Cotton Supply Association, 1862)
———, Ninth Annual Report of the Executive Committee (Manchester: Cotton Supply Association, 1868)
Cotton Supply Reporter, Cotton Supply Reporter (Manchester, 1 May 1865)
———, Cotton Supply Reporter (Manchester, 1 June 1865)
Craig, F. W. S., British Parliamentary Election Results 1832–1885, 2nd edn (London: Macmillan, 1989)
Darwin, John, ‘Imperialism and the Victorians: The Dynamics of Territorial Expansion’, English Historical Review, 112.447 (1997), 614–42 <https://doi.org/10.1093/ehr/cxii.447.614>
Davis, Ralph, The Industrial Revolution and British Overseas Trade (Leicester: Leicester University Press, 1979)
Earle, Edward Mead, ‘Egyptian Cotton and the American Civil War’, Political Science Quarterly, 41.4 (1926), 520–45 <https://doi.org/10.2307/2142228>
Ellison, Mary, Support for Secession (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1972)
Farnie, D. A., The English Cotton Industry and the World Market (Oxford: Clarendon, 1979)
Gallagher, John, and Ronald Robinson, ‘The Imperialism of Free Trade’, Economic History Review, 6.1 (1953), 1–15 <https://doi.org/10.2307/2591017>
Guelzo, Allen C., Fateful Lightning: A New History of the Civil War and Reconstruction (OUP USA, 2012)
Hansard, ‘House of Commons Debate on the Congo Free State’, 26 February 1908 <https://hansard.parliament.uk/commons/1908-02-26/debates/00dd9ca8-409f-4f67-bc24-823715fe3d4a/CongoFreeState>
———, ‘House of Commons Debate on the Cotton Supply’, 19 June 1862 <https://hansard.parliament.uk/commons/1862-06-19/debates/8425fcff-7850-41cd-a722-d97c8dadad3b/TheCottonSupply>
Harnetty, Peter, Imperialism and Free Trade (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1972)
———, ‘The Imperialism of Free Trade: Lancashire, India, and the Cotton Supply Question, 1861–1865’, Journal of British Studies, 6.1 (1966), 70–96 <https://doi.org/10.1086/385528>
———, ‘The Indian Cotton Duties Controversy, 1894–1896’, English Historical Review, 77.305 (1962), 684–702 <https://doi.org/10.1093/ehr/lxxvii.cccv.684>
Henderson, W. O., The Lancashire Cotton Famine 1861–65, 2nd edn (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1969)
Hobsbawm, Eric J., Industry and Empire, Rev. edn. (London: Penguin, 1999)
———, The Age of Capital: 1848–1875 (Weidenfeld & Nicholson, 1995)
Hobson, J. A., Imperialism, 1902
Hyam, Ronald, Britain’s Imperial Century, 1815–1914, 3rd edn (Springer, 2002)
Leacock, Seth, and David G. Mandelbaum, ‘A Nineteenth Century Development Project in India: The Cotton Improvement Program’, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 3.4 (1955), 334–51 <https://doi.org/10.1086/449693>
Lenin, Vladimir, ‘Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism’, in Collected Works (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1964)
Mill, John Stuart, On Liberty (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009) <https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139149785>
Mitchell, Timothy, Rule of Experts (University of California Press, 2002)
Owen, Roger, The Middle East in the World Economy, 1800–1914 (I. B. Tauris, 1993)
Porter, Bernard, The Lion’s Share: A Short History of British Imperialism, 1850–1983, 2nd edn (Longman, 1984)
Reid, Brian Holden, The American Civil War and the Wars of the Industrial Revolution (London: Cassell, 1999)
Roy, Tirthankar, Economic History of India, 1857–1947 (OUP India, 2011) <https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198074175.001.0001>
Seeley, John Robert, The Expansion of England (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010) <https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511783159>
Sexton, Jay, Debtor Diplomacy: Finance and American Foreign Relations in the Civil War Era 1837–1873 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005) <https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199281039.001.0001>
Tate, Jonathan Graham, ‘Industry, Technology and the Political Economy of Empire: Lancashire Industrialists and the Cotton Supply Question, c. 1850–1910’ (unpublished PhD Thesis, University of Aberdeen, 2015) <http://digitool.abdn.ac.uk/webclient/DeliveryManager?pid=228009>
The Economist (London, 21 September 1861)
——— (London, 4 October 1862)
Westminster and Foreign Quarterly Review (London, 1850)
Williams, Eric, Capitalism & Slavery, 2nd edn (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1994)